What happens to the total surplus in a market when the government imposed a tax?

Excise Taxes and Changes in Total Surplus

© 1999-2020, Douglas A.Ruby (06-04-2020)

An Excise Tax is a per-unit tax placed on the sale of a good (usually goods rather than services). These taxes often are imposed to generate revenue for federal, state and local governments and sometimes take the place of a per-use fee as in the case of a gasoline tax used to pay for roads, bridges and infrastructure. Excise taxes are sometimes considered to be Sin taxes in that they raise the price of certain products (tobacco and alcohol) with the goal of deterring use.

We often model the imposition of such taxes on the supply-side of the market. This corresponds to the administrative ease in collecting tax revenue -- fewer business relative to the number of consumers and business firms tend to keep better accounts. When an excise tax is imposed on the market, it cuts into both consumer surplus and producer surplus as the market price increases and consumer buy less of the product.

In the diagram below, move the Excise Tax slider to the right -- say a $10 exicse tax. Pay attention to the numbers in the status boxes. Notice that the supply curve S is modified to read S + T. The vertical distance between 'S' and 'S+T' is the amount of the exicse tax. Also note the change in Consumer Surplus and Producer Surplus. In the absence of the tax consumer surplus is equal to $80,000 ($90 - $50) x (4,000 units) and producer surplus is equal to $60,000 ($50 - $20) x (4,000 units). The combined value of consumer and producer surplus ($140,000) is known as Total Surplus and represents total surplus value to consumers and producers for participating in the market. As a tax is imposed the value of total surplus decreases. Some of it goes to the government in the form of Tax revenue, specifically the amount of the tax multiplied by the new equilibrium quantity.

For example with an excise tax (T) of $10.00:

New equilibrium quantity: 3,444.4 units
New (remaining) Consumer Surplus: [($90.00 - $55.60) x 3,444.40]/2 = $59,243.68
New (remaining) Producer Surplus: [($45.60 - $20) x 3,444.4]/2 = $44,088.32
New (remaining) Total Surplus: $59,243.68 + $ 44,088.32 = $103,332.00

The Deadweight Loss in this example is equal to the change in total surplus: $140,000 - $103,332.00 = $36,668.00 less the tax revenue collected:

Change in Total Surplus: $140,000 - $120,554 = $36,668.00
Tax Revenue collected: $10.00 x 3,444.4 units = $34,444.00
Difference or Deadweight Loss: $36,668.00 - $34,444.00 = $2,224.00

Deadweight loss is a meaure if inefficiency in resource allocation due to a distortion in the market -- in this case: imposing an excise tax. The need to generate government revenue comes with a cost in the form of lost consumer surplus that isn't recovered by any agent in the market-place

The relative steepness or flatness (more inelastic / more elastic) of the demand curve compared to the supply curve, affects the amount and split of revenue generated. If supply is relatively more elastic than demand, then the split (tax burden} of revenue generated falls more on the consumer.

It is useful to note that the imposition of the $10.00 per-unit tax only raised the market price by $5.60 -- consumers will substitute away from this good as it becomes relatively more expensive. So. $56.60 is paid to the seller (producer), but this seller needs to pay $10.00 per-unit, or $34,444.40 to the taxing-jurisdiction. Thus, the seller keeps $45.60 per-unit or $4.40 per-unit less than the market price in the absence of the tax.

For example:

Excise Tax: $10.00 per unit
Price paid by the consumer: $56.60, an increase of $5.60
Price received by the producer: $46.60, a reduction of $4.40
Tax paid by the consumer: $5.60 x 3,444.4 units = $19,288.64
Tax paid by the producer: $4.40 x 3,444.4 units = $15,155.36

In the example above, the change in price paid by the consumer ($5.60) is more than half of the per-unit tax of $10.00. If demand were to be relative flatter (demand is more price sensitive) when compared to supply, the increase in price to the consumer would be less and the seller would receive less net of taxes paid.

Concepts for Review:

  • Change in Consumer Surplus
  • Change in Producer Surplus
  • Excise Tax
  • Tax Burden
  • Tax Revenue
  • Total Surplus


Top of page related: Changes to Consumer Surplus previous: Producer Surplus next: Production in the Long Run Microeconomic Theory

Topic 4 Part 2: Applications of Supply and Demand

Learning Objectives

By the end of this section, you will be able to:

  • Distinguish between legal and economic tax incidence
  • Know how to represent taxes by shifting the curve and the wedge method
  • Understand the quantity and price affect from a tax
  • Describe why both taxes and subsidies cause deadweight loss

Taxes are not the most popular policy, but they are often necessary. We will look at two methods to understand how taxes affect the market: by shifting the curve and using the wedge method. First, we must examine the difference between legal tax incidence and economic tax incidence.

When the government sets a tax, it must decide whether to levy the tax on the producers or the consumers. This is called legal tax incidence. The most well-known taxes are ones levied on the consumer, such as Government Sales Tax (GST) and Provincial Sales Tax (PST). The government also sets taxes on producers, such as the gas tax, which cuts into their profits. The legal incidence of the tax is actually irrelevant when determining who is impacted by the tax. When the government levies a gas tax, the producers will pass some of these costs on as an increased price. Likewise, a tax on consumers will ultimately decrease quantity demanded and reduce producer surplus. This is because the economic tax incidence, or who actually pays in the new equilibrium for the incidence of the tax, is based on how the market responds to the price change – not on legal incidence.

Tax – Shifting the Curve

In Topic 3, we determined that the supply curve was derived from a firm’s Marginal Cost and that shifts in the supply curve were caused by any changes in the market that caused an increase in MC at every quantity level. This is no different for a tax. From the producer’s perspective, any tax levied on them is just an increase in the marginal costs per unit. To illustrate the effect of a tax, let’s look at the oil market again.

If the government levies a $3 gas tax on producers (a legal tax incidence on producers), the supply curve will shift up by $3. As shown in Figure 4.8a below, a new equilibrium is created at P=$5 and Q=2 million barrels. Note that producers do not receive $5, they now only receive $2, as $3 has to be sent to the government. From the consumer’s perspective, this $1 increase in price is no different than a price increase for any other reason, and responds by decreasing the quantity demanded for the higher priced good.

What happens to the total surplus in a market when the government imposed a tax?
Figure 4.7a

What if the legal incidence of the tax is levied on the consumers? Since the demand curve represents the consumers’ willingness to pay, the demand curve will shift down as a result of the tax. If consumers are only willing to pay $4/gallon for 4 million gallons of oil but know they will face a $3/gallon tax at the till, they will only purchase 4 million gallons if the ticket price is $1. This creates a new equilibrium where consumers pay a $2 ticket price, knowing they will have to pay a $3 tax for a total of $5. The producers will receive the $2 paid before taxes.

What happens to the total surplus in a market when the government imposed a tax?
Figure 4.7b

Note that whether the tax is levied on the consumer or producer, the final result is the same, proving the legal incidence of the tax is irrelevant.

Tax – The Wedge Method

Another method to view taxes is through the wedge method. This method recognizes that who pays the tax is ultimately irrelevant. Instead, the wedge method illustrates that a tax drives a wedge between the price consumers pay and the revenue producers receive, equal to the size of the tax levied.

As illustrated below, to find the new equilibrium, one simply needs to find a $3 wedge between the curves. The first wedge tested is only $0.7, followed by $1.5, until the $3.0 tax is found.

What happens to the total surplus in a market when the government imposed a tax?
Figure 4.7c

Market Surplus

Like with price and quantity controls, one must compare the market surplus before and after a price change to fully understand the effects of a tax policy on surplus.

What happens to the total surplus in a market when the government imposed a tax?
Figure 4.7d

Before

The market surplus before the tax has not been shown, as the process should be routine. Ensure you understand how to get the following values:

Consumer Surplus = $4 million

Producer Surplus  = $8 million

Market Surplus = $12 million

After

The market surplus after the policy can be calculated in reference to Figure 4.7d

Consumer Surplus (Blue Area) = $1 million

Producer Surplus (Red Area)= $2 million

Government Revenue (Green Area) = $6 million

Market Surplus = $9 million

Why is Government Included in Market Surplus

In our previous examples dealing with market surplus, we did not include any discussion of government revenue, since the government was not engaging in our market. Remember that market surplus is our metric for efficiency. If government was not included in this metric, it would not be very useful. In this case a million-dollar loss to government would be considered efficient if it resulted in a $1 gain to a consumer. To ensure that our metric for efficiency is still useful we must consider government when calculating market surplus.

As with the quota – both consumer and producer surplus decreased because of a reduced quantity. The difference is, since the price is changing, there is redistribution. This time, the redistribution is from consumers and producers to the government. Remember, only a change in quantity causes a deadweight loss. Price changes simply shift surplus around between consumers, producers, and the government.

Transfer and Deadweight Loss

Let’s look closely at the tax’s impact on quantity and price to see how these components affect the market.

What happens to the total surplus in a market when the government imposed a tax?
Figure 4.7e

Transfer – The Impact of Price

Due to the tax’s effect on price, areas A and C are transferred from consumer and producer surplus to government revenue.

Consumers to Government – Area A

Consumers originally paid $4/gallon for gas. Now, they are paying $5/gallon. The $1 increase in price is the portion of the tax that consumers have to bear. Despite the fact that the tax is levied on producers, the consumers have to bear a share of the price change. The size of this share depends on relative elasticity – a concept we will explore in the next section. This is because a decrease in price to producers means quantity supplied is falling, and in order to maintain equilibrium, quantity demanded must fall by an equal amount. This price change means the government collects $1 x 2 million gallons or $2 million in tax revenue from the consumers. This is a straight transfer from consumers to government and has no effect on market surplus.

Producers to Government – Area C

Originally, producers received revenue of $4/gallon for gas. Now, they receive $2/gallon. This $2 decrease is the portion of the tax that producers have to bear. This means that the government collects $2 x 2 million gallons or $4 million in tax revenue from the producers. This is a transfer from producers to the government.

As calculated, the government receives a total of $6 million in tax revenue, which is taken from consumers and producers. This has no impact on net market surplus.

Deadweight Loss – The Impact of Quantity

If we just considered a transfer of surplus, there would be no deadweight loss. In this case, though, we know that price changes come with a change in quantity. A higher price  for consumers will cause a decrease in the quantity demanded, and a lower price for producers will cause a decrease in quantity supplied. This reduction from equilibrium quantity is what causes a deadweight loss in the market since there are consumers and producers who are no longer able to buy and supply the good.

Consumer Surplus Decrease – Area B

Due to the increase in price, many consumers will switch away from oil to alternative options. This decrease in quantity demand of 1.5 million gallons of oil causes a deadweight loss of $1 million.

Producer Surplus Decrease – Area D

Producers, who now receive only $2.00/gallon for their production, will also decrease quantity supplied by 1.5 million gallons of oil. It is no coincidence that the size of the decrease is the same. When you create the wedge between consumers and producers, you are finding the quantity where the full amount of the tax is incurred but the market is still at equilibrium. Remember that quantity demanded must equal quantity supplied or the market will not be stable. This mirrored decrease in quantity ensures this is still the case. Notice, however, that the impact of this quantity drop causes a larger decrease in producer surplus than consumer surplus totalling $2 million. Again, this is due to elasticity, or the relative responsiveness to the price chance, which will be explored in more detail shortly.

Together, these decreases cause a $3 million deadweight loss (the difference between the market surplus before and market surplus after).

Subsidy

While a tax drives a wedge that increases the price consumers have to pay and decreases the price producers receive, a subsidy does the opposite. A subsidy is a benefit given by the government to groups or individuals, usually in the form of a cash payment or a tax reduction. A subsidy is often given to remove some type of burden, and it is often considered to be in the overall interest of the public. In economic terms, a subsidy drives a wedge, decreasing the price consumers pay and increasing the price producers receive, with the government incurring an expense.

In Topic 3, we looked at a case study of Victoria’s competitive housing market where high demand drove up prices. In response, the government has enacted many policies to allow low-income families to still become homeowners. Let’s look at the effects of one possible policy. (Note the following policy is unrealistic but allows for easy comprehension of the effect of subsidies).

What happens to the total surplus in a market when the government imposed a tax?
Figure 4.7f

In the market above, our efficient equilibrium begins at a price of $400,000 per home, with 40,000 homes being purchased. The government wants to substantially increase the number of consumers able to purchase homes, so it issues a $300,000 subsidy for any consumers purchasing a new home. This drives a wedge between what home buyers pay ($250,000) and what home builders receive ($550,000).

With all government policies we have examined so far, we have wanted to determine whether the result of the policy increases or decreases market surplus. With a subsidy, we want to do the same analysis. Unfortunately, because increases in surplus overlap on our diagram, it becomes more complicated. To simplify the analysis, the following diagram separates the changes to producers, consumers, and government onto different graphs.

What happens to the total surplus in a market when the government imposed a tax?
Figure 4.7g

Producers

The producers now receive $550,000 instead of $400,000, increasing quantity supplied to 60,000 homes. This increases producer surplus by areas A and B.

Consumers

The consumers now pay $250,000 instead of $400,000, increasing quantity demanded to 60,000 homes. This increases consumer surplus by areas C and D.

Government

The government now has to pay  $300,000 per home to subsidize the 60,000 consumers buying new homes (this policy would cost the government $18 billion!!) Graphically, this is equal to a decrease in government to areas A, B, C, D and E.

Result

Our total gains from the policy (to producers and consumers) are areas A, B, C and D, whereas total losses (the cost to the government) are areas A, B, C, D, and E. To summarize:

Areas A, B, C and D are transferred from the government to consumers and producers. 

Area E is a deadweight loss from the policy.

There are two things to notice about this example. First, the policy was successful at increasing quantity from 40,000 homes to 60,000 homes. Second, it resulted in a deadweight loss because equilibrium quantity was too high. Remember, anytime quantity is changed from the equilibrium quantity, in the absence of externalities, there is a deadweight loss. This is true for when quantity is decreased and when it is increased.

http://www.investopedia.com/terms/s/subsidy.asp

Summary

Taxes and subsidies are more complicated than a price or quantity control as they involve a third economic player: the government. As we saw, who the tax or subsidy is levied on is irrelevant when looking at how the market ends up. Note that the last three sections have painted a fairly grim picture about policy instruments. This is because our model currently does not include the external costs economic players impose to the macro-environment (pollution, disease, etc.) or attribute any meaning to equity. These concepts will be explored in more detail in later topics.

In our examples above, we see that the legal incidence of the tax does not matter, but what does? To determine which party bears more of the burden, we must apply the concept of relative elasticity to our analysis.

Glossary

Economic Tax Incidencethe distribution of tax based on who bears the burden in the new equilibrium, based on elasticityLegal Tax Incidencethe legal distribution of who pays the taxSubsidya benefit given by the government to groups or individuals, usually in the form of a cash payment or a tax reduction It is often to remove some type of burden, and it is often considered to be in the overall interest of the public

Exercises 4.7

Refer to the supply and demand curves illustrated below for the following THREE questions. Consider the introduction of a $20 per unit tax in this market.

What happens to the total surplus in a market when the government imposed a tax?

1. Which areas represent the loss to consumer AND producer surplus as a result of this tax?

a) k + f.
b) j + g.
c) k + j.
d) k + f + j + g.

2. Which areas represent the gain in government revenue as a result of this tax?

a) k + f.
b) j + g.
c) k + j.
d) k + f + j + g.

3. Which areas represent the deadweight loss associated with this tax?

a) f + g.
b) k – g.
c) j – f.
d) k + f + j + g.

4. Assume that the marginal cost of producing socks is constant for all sock producers, and is equal to $5 per pair. If government introduces a constant per-unit tax on socks, then which of the following statements is FALSE, given the after-tax equilibrium in the sock market? (Assume a downward-sloping demand curve for socks.)

a) Consumers are worse off as a result of the tax.
b) Spending on socks may either increase or decrease as a result of the tax.
c) Producers are worse off as a result of the tax.
d) This tax will result in a deadweight loss.

5. Refer to the supply and demand diagram below.

What happens to the total surplus in a market when the government imposed a tax?

If an subsidy of $3 per unit is introduced in this market, the price that consumers pay will equal ____ and the price that producers receive net of the subsidy will equal _____.

a) $2; $5.
b) $3; $6.
c) $4; $7.
d) $5; $8.

6. If a subsidy is introduced in a market, then which of the following statement is TRUE? Assume no externalities

a) Consumer and producer surplus increase but social surplus decreases.
b) Consumer and producer surplus decrease but social surplus increases.
c) Consumer surplus, producer surplus, and social surplus all increase.
d) Consumer surplus, producer surplus, and social surplus all decrease

Use the diagram below to answer the following TWO questions.

What happens to the total surplus in a market when the government imposed a tax?

7. If a $6 per unit tax is introduced in this market, then the price that consumers pay will equal ____ and the price that producers receive net of the tax will equal _____.

a) $10; $4.
b) $9; $3.
c) $8; $2.
d) $7; $1.

8. If a $6 per unit tax is introduced in this market, then the new equilibrium quantity will be:

a) 20 units.
b) 40 units.
c) 60 units.
d) None of the above.

9. Which of the following statements about the deadweight loss of taxation is TRUE? (Assume no externalities.)

a) If there is a deadweight loss, then the revenue raised by the tax is greater than the losses to consumer and producers.
b) If there is no deadweight loss, then revenue raised by the government is exactly equal to the losses to consumers and producers.
c) Both a) and b).
d) Neither a) nor b).

10. Which of the following correctly describes the equilibrium effects of a per-unit tax, in a market with NO externalities?

a) Consumer and producer surplus increase but social surplus decreases.
b) Consumer and producer surplus decrease but social surplus increases.
c) Consumer surplus, producer surplus, and social surplus all increase.
d) Consumer surplus, producer surplus, and social surplus all decrease.

11. Which of the following correctly describes the equilibrium effects of a per unit subsidy?

a) Consumer price rises, producer price falls, and quantity increases.
b) Consumer price falls, producer price falls, and quantity increases.
c) Consumer price rises, producer price rises, and quantity increases.
d) Consumer price falls, producer price rises, and quantity increases.

12. Refer to the supply and demand diagram below.

What happens to the total surplus in a market when the government imposed a tax?

If an output (excise) tax of $5 per unit is introduced in this market, the price that consumers pay will equal ____ and the price that producers receive net of the tax will equal _____.

a) $5; $10.
b) $6; $11.
c) $7; $12.
d) $8; $3.

13. Consider the supply and demand diagram below.

What happens to the total surplus in a market when the government imposed a tax?

If a $2 per unit subsidy is introduced, what will be the equilibrium quantity?

a) 40 units.
b) 45 units.
c) 50 units.
d) 55 units.

Consider the supply and demand diagram below. Assume that: (i) there are no externalities; and (ii) in the absence of government regulation the market supply curve is the one labeled S1.

What happens to the total surplus in a market when the government imposed a tax?

14. If a $5 per unit tax is introduced in this market, which area represents the deadweight loss?

a) a.
b) a + b.
c) b + c.
d) a + b + c.

What happens to total surplus in this market when the tax is imposed?

Regardless of whether a tax is imposed on a buyer or a seller, both will experience a reduction in surplus. Tax revenue is the dollar amount of tax collected. For an excise (or, per unit) tax, this is quantity sold multiplied by the value of the per unit tax. Tax revenue is counted as part of total surplus.

What happens to the total surplus in a market when the government imposes a tax quizlet?

What happens to the total surplus in a market when the government imposes a tax? Total surplus decreases. induces buyers to consume less, and sellers to produce less.

What is total surplus with tax?

The total surplus with a tax implies that the taxes have been deducted from the consumer and producer surplus. The total surplus is calculated by adding the consumer and producer surplus. A tax imposed will reduce the amount of total surplus and transfer it to the government in the form of tax revenue.

What causes total surplus to decrease?

Once the price rises above the market equilibrium price, then total surplus either starts to decline or no longer increases.